Copied from www.webreview.com to the Film-Tech server for archival use.


                      March 23, 2001  Platform Independent

                       The Hard Questions in Broadband Policy

                       By Andy Oram

                       During a period of life most people
                       try to forget, I learned from my high
                       school teachers the key to academic
                       success: how to score well on
                       standardized tests. "Answer the easy
                       questions first," they said, "then go
                       back and answer the hard ones if you
                       have time."

                       This is not a bad strategy for policy makers, either. It is the
                       route taken by Congress, the Federal Communications
                       Commission, and advocates for Internet service providers in
                       opening up new possibilities in broadband. They decide such
                       general questions as "Should all providers have access to
                       cable networks?" and leave the thorny issues of oversight,
                       cost, and equitability for later.

                       But maturity has taught this former high school student some
                       tough lessons. There is no intellectual training comparable to
                       20 years of showing technical documents to computer
                       engineers who rip them to shreds, plus five years of showing
                       policy papers to law professors who rip them to shreds. I've
                       found I can't hide from the hard questions.

                       So in this article I will focus on the hard questions that I see
                       as remaining to be answered in broadband. And I'll start from
                       the top, with the questions that are most difficult—because
                       these are the ones that generate the most points for the
                       right answers.

                       1. How do we provide truly universal access
                       to symmetric broadband?

                       I'm going to whisk right by cable modems and ADSL. (They
                       come further down the list of priorities.) Limited in their reach
                       and puny in upstream bandwidth, they were never meant to
                       be more than stopgaps. They don't meet the promise held
                       out by our society's leaders: to bring the entire public
                       high-speed connections that allow them to get education,
                       government information, telecommuting, reality TV, and
                       medical consultations everywhere, all the time.

                       Wireless is great in some geographic areas, but is hampered
                       by obstructions and weather in others. It's generally more
                       subject to crowding than wires, and somewhat less reliable.
                       Satellite promises universal accessibility but hasn't been
                       tested with large numbers of subscribers. Right now, it seems
                       like nothing will really meet our needs but fiber to the home.

                       It's always been assumed that fiber to the home is
                       prohibitively expensive to build. But that canard is now
                       challenged by Miles Fidelman, the founder and president of the
                       Center for Civic Networking, who advises local governments
                       on Internet technology and policy. He points out that fiber by
                       itself is cheaper than copper, because it's essentially made of
                       sand. Fiber is also lighter, which allows you to put more of it
                       on a pole without danger of toppling it.

                       Besides the cost of digging up the ground—which is being
                       done now anyway when new developments are built—the
                       reason fiber used to be expensive was the equipment used at
                       the endpoints. But the cost of this equipment has dropped to
                       the point where fiber is now completely competitive, coming to
                       between $1000 and $2000 per subscriber. Worldwide Packets
                       is one manufacturer already offering such equipment.

                       So, according to Fidelman, there is no economic reason to use
                       copper instead of fiber when building new developments. As
                       for established homes, several experts have suggested fiber
                       co-ops. In this model, customers band together to bring fiber
                       to a neighborhood. Each home has to pay for the short line
                       from the home to the pole. But by pooling resources,
                       neighbors can afford a line from their poles back to the central
                       office.

                       The radical notion of customers owning their own
                       infrastructure—kind of the ultimate in peer-to-peer
                       networking—has made headway in Canada, according to
                       François Menard, a product developer with years of experience
                       in telecom and now a fiber network project manager at the
                       consulting engineering firm IMS Experts-Conseils. Where the
                       E-Rate in the United States hamstrings schools into leasing
                       conventional service from phone companies, many schools in
                       Canada are investing the same money into stringing long fiber
                       cables to form their own private networks. Government
                       buildings are starting to do the same.

                       In Quebec, schools are spaced so that one can go from one
                       to another in no more than 75 kilometers. This makes it easy
                       to bypass the commercial Internet backbone and routing
                       system and to route traffic by the crude but effective
                       mechanism of hopping from one host to the next. This also
                       means that the users, not the Internet provider, define what
                       kinds of services are permitted.

                       "The regulatory regime in Canada is really favorable to building
                       infrastructure," says Menard. Anyone can become what is
                       termed a "nondominant carrier" by registering a
                       three-sentence letter. They can then attach to almost any
                       facilities.

                       The Canadian telecom commission created this favorable
                       situation without really meaning to: A 1995 decision gave
                       broad rights to budding carriers because the government was
                       desperate to break the dominant phone company's hold on
                       the telephone network. They didn't think about the Internet
                       at that point, but the radical decentralization created by the
                       bill now provides room for burgeoning Internet competition.

                       Now Australia is looking to Canada as a model for how to
                       promote broadband competition. Menard believes the way
                       forward is to allow practically anyone to register as a carrier,
                       give them the right to build facilities (such as by expropriating
                       public rights of way), and keep municipalities from granting
                       franchises to create monopoly carriers. In the U.S., by
                       contrast, competing phone carriers have great difficulty
                       stringing their own fiber, and instead are forced to buy it from
                       an existing carrier at high cost.

                       Fidelman and Menard, like many public-interest commentators,
                       believe the private phone monopolies are too happy with their
                       position to build the new infrastructure; their obsolete copper
                       is subsidized in a dozen ways by current regulatory regimes.
                       Governments or community organizations have to pick up the
                       slack. Even in the U.S., many local governments are trying to
                       build municipal fiber networks, or to offer service on existing
                       networks built by municipal electric companies. Ironically, they
                       often run up against lawsuits by phone companies.

                       These companies, having left small towns in the lurch and
                       declaring they can't afford to offer residents broadband
                       access, now try to stop the cities by claiming that municipal
                       networks are unfair competition! The hypocrisy of this
                       position is highlighted by the practice in most cities of offering
                       their networks in a nondiscriminatory manner to all ISPs.
                       Certainly, there are minor issues worth debating (such as
                       whether tax-free bonds should be used to fund networks that
                       compete with private ones) but the principal of municipal
                       broadband is in the best tradition of American self-reliance.

                       Whether or not local governments build municipal networks,
                       Fidelman recommends they take other actions to allow the
                       development of broadband. These include updating building
                       codes if necessary, and requiring developers to lay the conduit
                       for fiber when digging up neighborhoods.

                       Bruce Kushnick, who is the executive director of the New
                       Networks Institute, a public-interest group doing telecom
                       research, pointed out in his book The Unauthorized Biography
                       of the Baby Bells & Info-Scandal that local phone companies
                       made promises throughout the 1980s and 1990s to build
                       fiber to the home for millions of Americans. Utility
                       commissions across the country reduced regulation and
                       allowed the Bells to collect billions in fees to build out fiber.

                       Of course, it turned out that fiber to the home was incredibly
                       expensive at that point, and there were few applications to
                       make it worthwhile. So the Bells never built the network.
                       (They kept the money, though.) Kushnick thinks that, if the
                       fiber had been laid, a wealth of new businesses would have
                       sprung up to offer services and we wouldn't be experiencing
                       the Internet downturn we have now.

                       2. Can broadband ever be affordably priced?

                       The plague of failures among companies offering ADSL
                       indicates that something is wrong with current pricing. Some
                       people hasten to round up the usual suspects—incumbent
                       telephone companies. Kushnick points to numerous
                       complaints filed in various states by ISPs documenting that
                       incumbents offer worse service to competing ISPs than they
                       offer to the company affiliated with the incumbent. Overpricing
                       is also alleged, as in a ruling by the Kentucky Public Service
                       Commission that BellSouth discriminated against Iglou
                       Internet Services. The complaint was one frequently echoed
                       around the country: BellSouth charged high rates for
                       purchasing single lines and reserved reasonable, wholesale
                       rates for extremely large purchases that would be available
                       only to a very large service provider. In a market where small
                       ISPs line up customers a handful at a time, this pricing
                       excludes competition.

                       But other observers express a more thoroughgoing
                       pessimism. It's true, they say, that ADSL from the incumbent
                       phone companies (and cable modem access from cable
                       companies) is priced so low that there is no room for
                       competition. But perhaps, they say, it's not due to
                       overcharging. Instead, incumbents are cross-subsidizing their
                       own services.

                       For an incumbent phone company, phone bills from the mass
                       of captive phone users could help pay for ADSL. For a cable
                       company, Internet service is almost always bundled with
                       television and other services, so determining the actual costs
                       is impossible for an outsider. Some companies apparently
                       absorb the cost of Internet service in order to hold on to
                       customers who might otherwise take their television business
                       elsewhere. The partnerships between cable companies and
                       ISPs (Excite@Home and Road Runner) show that the cable
                       companies are explicitly subsidizing Internet access through
                       their content offerings.

                       And even if an ISP managed to get a cheap line to the
                       customer, it would still have to reserve bandwidth for that
                       customer on the line it buys to its network access point (one
                       of the major Internet routers). For instance, an ADSL line
                       carrying up to 1.4 Megabits to a customer has to be backed
                       up with the equivalent of a 1.4 Megabit T1 line on the other
                       end.

                       And the equipment required to connect to the phone
                       company or cable company system is extremely expensive.
                       According to Chris Savage, head of the Telecom/Internet
                       Practice at Cole, Raywid & Braverman, it will get worse if
                       phone companies continue doing things like SBC's Project
                       Pronto.

                       Today, most neighborhoods still have copper running from
                       the company's central offices to the home. The distance can
                       range up to several miles and can contain clunky equipment
                       that rules out the use of DSL. Project Pronto is stringing fiber
                       all the way to within a mile or so of each home (often less).

                       This is an excellent solution for the incumbent phone
                       company, but now an ISP wanting to offer service comparable
                       to the incumbent—or a competing phone company serving
                       ISPs—has a very unpleasant choice. It could reproduce what
                       the incumbent is doing and string its own fiber to each
                       neighborhood of 500 to 1000 homes. But since this is not at
                       all cost-effective; most competing carriers and ISPs will
                       instead be reduced to reselling the phone company's service,
                       or simply letting the phone company carry its traffic.

                       While most neighborhoods still have copper running from the
                       company's central offices and the home, Project Pronto is
                       stringing fiber past the central offices to within a mile or so of
                       each home (often less). Now, an ISP wanting to offer service
                       comparable to the phone company—or a competing phone
                       company serving ISPs—would have to string its own fiber to
                       each neighborhood of 500 to 1000 homes in order to get to
                       the clean copper needed to offer DSL services. This is not at
                       all cost-effective; most competing carriers and ISPs will
                       instead be reduced to reselling the phone company's service,
                       or simply letting the phone company carry its traffic.

                       Lawrence Hecht, creator of the Internet Public Policy Network,
                       which identifies experts that provide consultation to ISPs and
                       others on Internet policy, still holds out hope. He says, "There
                       are two popular business models for providing
                       high-bandwidth content: Get an exclusive relationship with
                       the content provider, or use the network access points to
                       cache content." The first option is the well-known strategy
                       pursued by cable companies, most notably AOL Time Warner.
                       It's limited to large conglomerates and holds the risk of
                       discriminating in terms of content. But the second option is
                       available to small ISPs through the strategy of banding
                       together and buying access to network access points.

                       "Vertical integration of the content and the pipe is not
                       necessary," says Hecht. "What's really necessary is to get
                       content near the edges of the network where you want it to
                       be delivered."

                       For small nonprofit and educational organizations, Hecht looks
                       for government support. It would be great, he suggests, if
                       companies involved in streaming media and caching donated
                       servers to nonprofit and educational use, while lobbying
                       governments to provide matching funds for these institutions
                       to develop content. For the companies, it would educate
                       customers about their services and promote wider use. "If
                       you're talking about democratizing the media," claims Hecht,
                       "you can't stick to text; you have to consider streaming audio
                       and video."

3. How do we promote competition on the
                       existing local telephone and cable networks?

                       Five years after the Telecom Act tried to open up competition
                       in U.S. phone service, it has emerged only for sizeable
                       businesses—and other countries have even less competition.
                       While incumbent Bells are supposed to foster competition
                       before they can offer long-distance service in their areas,
                       some are getting into long distance on the basis of pretty thin
                       evidence. Congress is threatening to cut the whole discussion
                       short and give the Bells everything they want.

                       And some critics of the incumbents say that long distance is
                       not a very juicy carrot anyway. According to Savage, the
                       incumbent's costs for providing a local connection between a
                       long distance company and an end user run about 0.2 cents
                       per minute, perhaps even less. But the incumbent charges 2
                       cents per minute (10 times that amount) to the long-distance
                       company in federally mandated access charges. So the local
                       companies are already profiting nicely without having to offer
                       long-distance service directly.

                       Cable in the U.S. is a horse of an entirely different color—what
                       Menard calls a "gray-zone," because the FCC and the courts
                       are still trying to decide what regulatory regime it falls under.
                       It was not the FCC, but the Federal Trade Commission that
                       insisted as part of its consent decree approving the AOL Time
                       Warner merger that competing ISPs be allowed onto their
                       cable network.

                       American ISPs are looking to models from Canada, where the
                       Canadian Radio-Television and Telecommunications
                       Commission ruled as far back as 1996 that nonprogramming
                       services over cable could be regulated as a common carrier.
                       Chris Taylor of the Canadian Cable Television Association
                       says, "Third-party access is a reality here in Canada. At this
                       point in time, it's a limited reality, but details about tariffs
                       (rates for ISPs to lease service from cable companies) are still
                       being worked out by the CRTC, and it's likely to grow. Some
                       cable companies were quite keen on third-party access from
                       the beginning. But all companies have accepted that it's the
                       reality and are working to make it successful."

                       Legal classifications, and even regulated tariffs, do not suffice
                       to create a level playing field. The devil is in the details. Cable
                       companies can manipulate the underlying architecture to
                       discriminate against competing ISPs in many ways:

                            While routing packets to the ISP (by checking the source
                            address or by other means), the cable company can
                            choose a lower quality of service (QoS).
                            The cable company can simply divert its own customers'
                            traffic to the Internet before it reaches the Point of
                            Interconnection where traffic for other ISPs have to go
                            to be routed to the proper ISPs.
                            The cable company can put competing ISPs on an
                            entirely different router, once again with a lower quality
                            of service.

                       These things are not a problem in Canada, Taylor claims. "By
                       law, the cable companies cannot offer a different quality of
                       service to third-party ISPs." The difficulties we've had in the
                       U.S. with local phone competition over the past five years
                       offer the lesson that true competition requires lots of
                       regulation, and lots of checking up, when one competitor is
                       using facilities provided by another.

                       And the longer we wait, the more people will sign up for the
                       cable company's service (which they are pushing
                       aggressively), and the more inertia will emerge against
                       changing ISPs. This is particularly true if customers who want
                       to switch have to buy a new cable modem to replace one that
                       only understands how to reach a single ISP.

                       4. How do we provide adequate resources on
                       shared cable networks?

                       A cable network is like an Ethernet LAN: when one person is
                       sending a packet, everybody else has to wait. This means that
                       high-bandwidth use on the cable network is a zero-sum
                       game, and can easily degenerate into a tragedy of the
                       commons. Furthermore, the small upstream bandwidth
                       requires companies to ban servers and even peer-to-peer
                       applications—like the barely alive Napster.

                       Many ISPs pride themselves on offering guaranteed quality of
                       service and fancy configurations such as VPNs. On cable
                       networks, most of these enhancements are prohibited by
                       cable companies in order to conserve shared bandwidth. Small
                       ISPs stay alive by differentiating themselves. But on a cable
                       network, they have limited options to do so. And the options
                       are at some remove from their primary job of moving traffic,
                       lying in such ancillary services as Web hosting, backups, and
                       customer service (assuming the customer problem is not on
                       the cable network).

                       Taylor warns, "ISPs have to be aware that as their use of the
                       shared network grows, and as the number of ISPs sharing it
                       grows, congestion will occur. And it takes time to segment the
                       network to relieve the congestion. But the cable companies'
                       own customers use the same network as all the other ISPs
                       and are subject to the same capacity constraints. So there's a
                       huge incentive for the cable company to make sure the
                       network is as efficient as possible."

                       Can multiple ISPs peacefully co-exist? Taylor says,
                       "Requirements are being imposed on cable modems to ensure
                       that the quality of service to that modem's user, as well as
                       usage across the whole network, is appropriate." Fidelman
                       suggests that the quality-of-service features on modern
                       routers might be used to apportion bandwidth to different
                       ISPs.

                       5. Who will pay for content?

                       Although infrastructure companies are hurting these days, the
                       really serious wounds have been sustained by content
                       providers. The value of banner ads is increasingly being
                       questioned, simply because so many users ignore them. The
                       science of banner ads is also being questioned. Agencies
                       rubbed their hands with glee when they realized that
                       click-throughs could be counted, but that's actually a pretty
                       crude measure of an ad's reach. Meanwhile, paying by the
                       click-through has a distorting side effect: it insulates
                       advertisers from their own bad judgment. They don't have to
                       worry about paying much for advertising on a site whose
                       readers aren't interested in them.

                       Perhaps you don't trust corporate sponsors; you could argue
                       that the Web would become smaller but better if content were
                       provided by educational institutions and nonprofits. These,
                       too, however, find it a strain to keep providing updated,
                       high-quality content. It takes highly trained staff just to make
                       sure links are visible in the right places and go to the right
                       pages, much less format and display new material in a timely
                       manner. Micropayment schemes are complicated, will take a
                       long time to put into place, and don't reflect the kind of casual
                       browsing experience most people look for. So by the time we
                       hook up all Americans to broadband, they may have nothing
                       worth looking at.

                       6. What will happen to wages and working
                       conditions?

                       We all talk about progress and innovation in the
                       communications industry. Most of the time we assume that
                       goes along with competition and privatization. But while those
                       often have benefits, they are also sometimes code words for
                       union-busting. It would not be fair to lower costs by making
                       workers put in 12-hour days (one of the main issues in last
                       year's Verizon strike) or slashing their wages in half. To sum
                       up, people are infrastructure too.


                       Andy andyo@oreilly.com, is an editor at O'Reilly & Associates
                       and moderator of the Cyber Rights mailing list for Computer
                       Professionals for Social Responsibility. This article represents
                       his views only.